Mechanisms of political systems in managing societies with a high population density: China as a model

Abstract

With over 1.4 billion people, China faces immense challenges in governing and managing its large and dense population. This paper analyzes the mechanisms and strategies employed by China’s political system to maintain stability and drive development in a complex, rapidly changing society. It examines how China’s centralized, authoritarian system allows it to mobilize resources, implement sweeping reforms, and tightly regulate society. However, China also faces limitations and risks from its political structure, including an inflexibility to adapt quickly, tendencies towards corruption, and potential for unrest as economic disparities widen. China’s development model offers insights on both the opportunities and pitfalls of authoritarian governance in dense urban environments facing pressures from growth, inequality and globalization.

Introduction

China’s political system has enabled the country to achieve rapid economic growth and rising standards of living while maintaining social control over its massive population. Since opening up reforms in 1979, China’s GDP has grown over 9% per year, lifting 800 million people out of poverty (World Bank, 2019). Life expectancy has risen from 43 years in 1960 to 77 years today (Banister & Hill, 2004). China succeeded in transforming from a rural, agrarian society to an industrialized urban nation in just a few decades.

However, enormous challenges remain. China must now manage dense megacities like Shanghai, with over 24 million people, as well as respond to crises like the COVID-19 epidemic. China’s growth has also created greater disparities, with a wealthy urban elite and millions still in poverty. Air pollution, food safety scandals and labor abuses show the stresses from China’s industrialization. The political legitimacy of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) rests on continually improving living standards. With an aging population, China may grow old before it grows truly prosperous (Economy, 2018).

This paper analyzes China’s political system and governance strategies in dealing with its large, dense population. It assesses the structure of China’s authoritarian regime, the mechanisms for control and flexibility, and capacity to mobilize resources for development. China’s model demonstrates both the potential and limitations of centralized political systems in rapidly developing, urbanizing societies. The analysis provides insights on governing crowded megacities facing environmental stresses, inequality, migration and other challenges.

Political Structure

China has an authoritarian one-party political system dominated by the CCP. The CCP has over 90 million members, making it the largest political party in the world (Lawrence & Martin, 2013). The party permeates all levels of government and society. China’s constitution affirms the CCP’s leading role. There are eight “democratic” parties that participate in the political system, but they are small and must align with CCP priorities. Elections occur for local representative bodies, but open campaigning is limited and most candidates are CCP members. China does not have an independent judiciary or rule of law. The courts and legal system serve the interests of the CCP.

The pinnacle of power is the Standing Committee of the Politburo, which has seven members. The General Secretary of the CCP leads both the Politburo and the party. The outgoing President appoints the next General Secretary, who then assumes the Presidency. The Premier leads the administrative State Council. In practice, the General Secretary (currently Xi Jinping) holds the most power. The CCP Central Committee has over 200 full members who meet annually to approve major decisions. The CCP convenes a National Congress every five years to establish direction and leadership for the next term.

The CCP sits atop a parallel structure of government administration and Party committees down to the provincial, city, county and village level. Party committees exist within all agencies and major organizations in society. This allows the CCP to penetrate all aspects of daily life and governance. The formal state leadership at each level mirrors the Party committee, creating unified command. China is administratively divided into 22 provinces, five autonomous regions, four mega-cities called municipalities, and two special administrative regions (Hong Kong and Macau). Provincial leaders carry the dual titles of CCP Secretary and Governor. Beneath provinces are prefectures, counties, and townships. Village committees form the lowest level handling grassroots administration.

China’s authoritarian system concentrates decision-making at the top levels of the CCP. The senior leaders formulate national policies and exercise control through the CCP’s penetration of society, the state bureaucracy, the courts and security forces. Stability is maintained through a mixture of coercion, surveillance, and responsive governance delivering improved living standards. The CCP sees state power and capacity as essential to managing China’s huge population and territory. However, the centralized structure also poses risks from corruption, group-think, and slow response times to crises and social changes.

Mechanisms of Control and Response

The CCP deploys a mixture of rigid monitoring and selective flexibility to maintain control while allowing measured reforms. Stability maintenance is the overriding priority to sustain CCP rule. Meanwhile, the CCP seeks to tackle problems that could undermine legitimacy, such as poverty, pollution and corruption (Heilmann & Stepan, 2016). The CCP is always scanning for potential threats in society. If unrest grows, the CCP can swing from flexibility to repression.

Surveillance and censorship are pervasive. Government monitors social media, chat apps and cell phones. Criticism of the CCP is quickly censored. The “Great Firewall” blocks foreign websites and apps. A “social credit system” tracks individuals’ behaviors and can limit travel and activities. The CCP retains ultimate authority over courts, police and security agencies. Security funding exceeds official military spending (Economy, 2018). New high-tech surveillance methods enhance control, including facial recognition cameras, mandatory DNA samples in one region, and phone scanning at checkpoints. These digital tools amplify the party’s reach down to minute details of people’s daily lives.

However, reliance on coercion has limits. Shutting down all criticism would deny valuable feedback. Stifling innovation and change contradicts China’s development goals. Thus, the regime employs flexible social management to address selected issues (Heilmann & Stepan, 2016). For example, local environmental protests are often tolerated because pollution is an acknowledged challenge. If unrest grows, authorities might crack down but also address underlying problems. When issues align with CCP interests, the system can show adaptability. Local experiments with reduced bureaucracy or improved services can later go national. Xi’s anti-corruption drive led to prosecutions of hundreds of officials, although elite power struggles also motivated the purge.

The CCP funnels significant resources into monitoring public opinion for signs of dissent. Local cadres face pressures from both above to implement central directives, and below to address needs of citizens (Truex, 2016). If grievances simmer, local authorities may quietly mitigate problems before they escalate and hit official metrics. For example, financial compensation to polluted villages is often kept quiet. The CCP recognizes that “rigid stability” from brute coercion risks triggering bigger blowback versus flexible methods to release pressure (Chen, 2016). For instance, authorities may allow some non-disruptive protests as “steam release valves” (Trevaskes, 2010).

However, local responsiveness occurs under the radar without broader reforms. Addressing symptoms lets the CCP avoid tackling root problems that might threaten its power. There are limits on bottom-up civil society due to distrust of autonomous organizing. If flexibly addressing problems requires loosening political control, repression overrides responsiveness. Overall, CCP flexibility is selective and tactical rather than signaling fundamental reforms (Heilmann & Stepan, 2016). The system reaches just far enough to take the edge off discontent without undermining the CCP’s monopoly on power.

Governing Capacity and Mobilization

A major advantage of China’s centralized system is the capacity to mobilize resources. The CCP regime can implement major initiatives across all provinces and down through the bureaucracy. Xi’s consolidation of power strengthened this capability compared to recent decades of fragmented authority. Once the CCP leadership reaches consensus, national policies can rollout quickly. There is little legislative or judicial oversight to slow executive action. Stability maintenance like COVID lockdowns can also be imposed uniformly. Local officials have direct incentives to fulfill CCP directives because promotion depends on meeting targets. However, implementation gaps and foot-dragging persist where local interests diverge from central priorities. For example, Xi’s limits on coal faced pushback from provinces economically dependent on coal power.

The CCP plans long-term strategies leveraging the full resources of the state. China’s rise depended on strategic investments guided by Five Year plans and industrial policies to build manufacturing capacity, technology, and infrastructure. The current 13th Five Year Plan (2016-2020) focuses on innovation, sustainability and economic rebalancing. These plans are implemented through the unified state-party bureaucratic system. China’s $500 billion Belt and Road initiative linking infrastructure across Eurasia displays unprecedented scale and vision. Authoritarian governments arguably have advantages in coordinating across agencies versus democratic systems plagued by turf wars between ministries (Halper, 2010). China’s strategic planning leverages all levers of national power.

The regime invests heavily in “performance legitimacy” by continually improving living standards (Bell, 2015). As the economy expanded, the CCP could point to pragmatically delivering outcomes. Much state capacity is directed at modernizing the economy and creating jobs to satisfy rising expectations. The CCP is constantly generating targets and metrics to assess results. Many local officials were incentivized and evaluated based on economic growth and social stability. So long as living standards kept improving, officials gained latitude in meeting CCP demands. However, now the economy is slowing and skewed to benefit urban elites over rural poor. Performing legitimacy will require a shift from quantity to quality of growth.

In sum, China’s political system concentrates resources and authority for national mobilization. The CCP regime perceives state capacity as essential to lead China’s development while maintaining control over society. However, as the easy phase of fast growth ends, governing capacity will face greater stresses.

Development Model

China followed a state-led, authoritarian development model to industrialize and urbanize. This approach achieved tremendous economic and social gains as China opened up to the world economy. However, the model now faces limitations as China reaches the middle-income level and confronts complex challenges from growth.

Rural reforms started under Deng Xiaoping in the 1980s dismantled collective farming and allowed entrepreneurship. Township and village enterprises (TVEs) sprung up under local government leadership. Export-oriented manufacturing took advantage of China’s cheap labor through special economic zones that attracted foreign direct investment (Heilmann, 2017). Light industry and low-end manufacturing fueled growth through the 1990s and 2000s. Government expenditure on infrastructure like roads, electricity, rail and ports enabled development in the interior.

This statist model followed an “unorthodox path” distinct from the Washington Consensus neoliberal policies promoted for developing countries (Halper, 2010). The state retained control over land, key industries and the financial system. Industrial policies supported targeted sectors and firms, especially state-owned enterprises (SOEs). Local officials aggressively promoted investment and growth. Premier Zhu Rongji reformed state-owned firms in the 1990s, privatizing many smaller ones while retaining the large SOEs. Finance was gradually liberalized. Fiscal and monetary stimulus responded aggressively to any economic slowdowns.

Capitalist elements like entrepreneurship thrived under state guidance. Private firms generate over 60% of growth and employment, although SOEs still dominate strategic sectors (Heilmann, 2017). Foreign investment and exports led growth, making China the “factory of the world.” Rural migrants flooded into cities for manufacturing jobs. Local governments actively managed urbanization, building extensive infrastructure and housing. Megacities with tens of millions arose almost overnight, like Shenzhen growing from 300,000 to over 12 million people from 1985 to 2017. Urbanization rates soared from 18% in 1978 to 60% today.

This authoritarian development model achieved tremendous poverty reduction and industrial upgrades. China became an upper middle-income country by 2010. The CCP argues its meritocratic governance led by technical experts drove rational decisions for the nation as a whole. Concentrated power could pursue long time horizons, unlike politicians facing short election cycles. Elite power struggles occurred but did not derail consistent economic strategies (Halper, 2010). Rapid implementation of reforms presented a sharp contrast to gridlock in Indian democracy.

However, China’s growth model is hitting limits as the economy matures. The “demo-graphic dividend” from a large working-age population is disappearing as the population ages. Rural surplus labor for manufacturing is drying up. Costs and wages are rising, eroding China’s competitive advantage in export sectors. Environmental damage from growth threatens public health. Inequality is rising sharply. China’s Gini coefficient reached .49 in the 2000s. The top 1% own nearly a third of wealth (Li & Wan, 2015). Local debt has ballooned to dangerous levels from overinvestment. The financial system faces risks from speculative lending.

Most concerning, China is stuck in the “middle income trap” as catching up growth from technology transfer is exhausted. Productivity and innovation are lagging advanced economies. Attempts to move up the value chain like Made in China 2025 are faltering. Growth is slowing down, falling below 6% before the pandemic. The former development model cannot drive further advancement. Painful reforms are required to boost productivity, spur innovation, and rejig the state sector. However, vested interests may block reforms that erode their economic rents. The political system has also become more rigid under Xi, with power concentrated in a few hands. CCP technocrats may lack the creative thinking needed for this uncertain transition.

In summary, China’s unique authoritarian development path achieved tremendous gains but now faces pitfalls. Governing China’s huge population through the middle-income trap and demographic crisis poses an unprecedented challenge.

Risks and Challenges

Several risks and challenges hang over China’s development trajectory and the CCP’s political control. An inflexible political system led by a narrow elite could struggle to adapt to mounting complex problems. The CCP also faces rising expectations and demands from an increasingly sophisticated public.Xi’s tilt towards rigid stability maintenance heightens pressures within a brittle system. Major risks include widening inequality, demographic decline, environmental crisis, economic stagnation and loss of legitimacy. The timeline for China to become a fully developed nation is compressing while the difficulty of reforms is increasing. Meanwhile, global attitudes are hardening against China’s authoritarian model as its assertive policies from Xinjiang to Hong Kong spark pushback.

Rising inequality threatens social stability and CCP legitimacy. The development model favored urban areas and coastal regions over rural interior zones. Income gaps have widened sharply since the 2000s between urban and rural households, and between coastal and western provinces (Li & Wan, 2015). China has over 600 billionaires and millions more in the new middle class. Yet 2005 estimates had over 150 million people living below the World Bank poverty line of $1/day. Inequality is rising within cities between educated urban professionals and migrants working insecure, low-paid jobs with few benefits or social security. Women and minorities suffer greater discrimination. Tax and fiscal policies favor the wealthy.

The hukou system of residency permits entrenches inequality by denying rural migrants access to urban social services. Hukou reform is progressing slowly despite pressures from urbanization and an aging society. Significant inequality persists between urban hukou holders and migrants in terms of health care, education, pensions, and employment rights in the cities. Rapid urbanization was accompanied by evictions, land grabs, and lack of consultation, sparking thousands of local protests each year. Pollution and environmental damage disproportionately affect the poor and rural areas. Unrest could surge if inequality hollows out the urban middle class that thus far largely accepted the social compact of rising prosperity under CCP rule.

China faces a demographic timebomb from an aging population and shrinking workforce. The legacy of the One Child Policy means China is aging rapidly before incomes reach developed levels. The over 65 population will rise from 9% in 2010 to 25% by 2040 (Peng, 2011). With reduced family support under the One Child Policy, huge burdens will fall on healthcare and pension systems. The working age population peaked in 2015 due to low fertility rates. China’s potential growth rate could fall to just 3% due to negative demographics (Kania, 2018). Japan and South Korea grew old before getting rich, creating “prematurely greying societies” (Cai & Lu, 2013). China could follow this trajectory.

Pension shortfalls already exceed $328 billion (Wang, 2017). The social security system covers only half the population. Expanding health care and elder care will be extremely costly. Rural areas lack robust systems. Gender imbalances from the One Child Policy reach 30 million excess males. These “bare branches” face bleak social prospects and could spur violence and crime. Further loosening of birth limits might not help much given entrenched low fertility preferences. Demographic decline could stifle innovation and dynamism if working age populations stagnate. The CCP will struggle to drive continued development with shrinking workforces supporting larger elderly cohorts. Any political disruptions or environmental disasters could render demographic plans irrelevant.

China faces massive environmental pollution after decades pursuing unconstrained GDP growth. Only 1% of China’s cities meet World Health Organization air standards due to coal power, vehicle emissions and factories (Economy, 2018). Water is dangerously contaminated from industrial waste and agriculture. Soil suffers heavy metal and toxic pollution from mining and manufacturing. Desertification affects a quarter of China’s land, expanding every year. China is the world’s largest carbon emitter. Health effects from pollution plague major cities, with some studies finding it takes 3 years off average lifespans in the north. Food and consumer scares like toxic baby formula erode basic trust.

The government now acknowledges the environment risks economic productivity, public health, and political stability. Policies aim to cut coal reliance, improve air quality, expand renewables, clean up watersheds, and strengthen environmental regulations. China invested over $100 billion in green industries during the 2008 crisis. In 2015 Xi vowed to build an “ecological civilization.” However, enforcement still lags behind rhetoric. Local officials are evaluated on economic targets, not sustainability. Polluting industries wield influence. Tough reforms are required to escape the environmental disaster of China’s growth model, but vested interests will resist. With severe degradation locked-in even under optimal policies, China faces ecological and health crises that could overwhelm public finances. Environmental stresses could trigger unrest, drive away foreign capital, and exact huge healthcare costs.

China’s economic growth model is running out of steam, but reforms to spur innovation and productivity are progressing slowly. Transitioning towards innovation, services and consumption-led growth requires competitive markets, rule of law, and reductions in state dominance. However, reforms are tangled in bureaucratic and political feuds between agencies. Local governments oppose shrinking the state sector that provides stable revenues and jobs. “Zombie” SOEs stay open to avoid unemployment, dragging down productivity. Attempts at “mixed ownership” and private inflows into SOEs had limited impact (Heilmann, 2017). Barriers persist against private firms in sectors like banking, energy, telecom and transportation. Cutting excess industrial capacity faces resistance Financial risks are rising from speculative bubbles in real estate and risky lending by loosely regulated shadow banks. Local governments got hooked on land sales for revenues, creating property oversupply. After massive stimulus during the Global Financial Crisis, China’s debt soared from 150% of GDP in 2008 to over 260% in 2017 (Biswas, 2018). Hidden municipal and provincial debts are widely considered unsustainable. Xi’s anti-corruption drive chilled a vast grey economy of bribery that greased wheels at all levels. But rule of law and impartial regulation are still lacking. Foreign firms face skepticism and restrictions. China’s closed capital account and controlled currency pose challenges for deeper integration.

If productivity and innovation fail to advance, China could remain stuck as a middle-income country unable to move up the value chain. Economists warn China could grow old before it gets rich. Moreover, the global context is less favorable than during China’s ascendance in the 1990s and 2000s. Advanced economies face protracted weakness. Trade conflict and tech rivalry with the US threaten China’s access to Western markets, capital and technology. China’s early tech successes like its mobile payments system cannot readily be exported abroad due to lack of openness and distrust.

Politically, the CCP faces rising expectations from citizens for accountability, quality-of-life improvements, and participation. A more sophisticated public expects better services, clean air, affordable housing and integrity from officials. With slowing growth, performing legitimacy requires delivering results beyond just GDP. But governance remains opaque with limited channels for civic input or media oversight of abuses. Repression of lawyers, activists and intellectuals alienates educated urbanites. Youth express individualism at odds with propaganda and censorship. Despite rising nationalism, the current social contract depends on steady growth and mobility. A middle class society is already emerging in major cities, with expanded personal choices. If the CCP cannot satisfy rising expectations, its legitimacy may falter.

Xi’s strongman politics also carries risks by removing restraints on power. Xi forced through the abolition of term limits, enabling him to rule indefinitely. This raises prospects of bad decisions being made without input or oversight. Inner-party dissent is silenced as Xi demands total loyalty. During previous reforms, Deng Xiaoping sought to institutionalize collective leadership to prevent the extremes of Maoism. But Xi’s persona dominates over institutions. Since administrative systems depend heavily on top-down oversight, weakening institutions opens space for corruption and policy missteps. Xi’s coercive apparatus also limits how effectively local officials address livelihood issues. Stability maintenance alone cannot tackle complex challenges like inequality, environmental damage and the middle-income trap. If crises emerge, the system may lack flexibility to respond.

There are no clear processes or precedents for leadership transition in this new era. Factional oligarchy could reemerge to deadlock or derail policies after Xi departs. Younger generations expect more voice in society and policy choices beyond just material gains. If China’s development stalls under rigid authoritarian politics, Educated urbanites and youth may demand space for civic participation and accountability. Sudden loosening could destabilize the system but refusal to adapt risks explosive pressures.

Overall, Xi’s strongman approach may prove ill-suited to ushering China through the turbulent middle-income transition in a complex, modern society.

China Model in Comparative Perspective

China’s experience offers lessons on both the potential and limitations of authoritarian governance for development and managing high-density populations. On one hand, China’s centralized system had advantages in mobilizing resources, driving infrastructure investment and strategic planning. The system could achieve results and implement policies across society in areas prioritized by the leadership. For developing massive cities almost overnight or undertaking mega-projects like high-speed rail, state capacity proved critical. If incentives align, local officials effectively execute infrastructure and urban transformation. Rapid policy implementation allows playing catch-up with advanced economies.

However, there are inherent contradictions in trying to drive world-leading innovation with closed, coercive governance. Innovation flourishes through open flows of ideas, decentralization and diverse creative talents. Concentrating power excessively risks group-think and detachment from society. China’s closed system induces constant fears of external contamination – whether from foreign influences or autonomous civil organizations. But modern societies are too complex for top-down control over every aspect. Excessive stability maintenance creates brittle systems. With Xi’s power grab, these tensions are heightening.

Singapore offers similarities as an authoritarian capitalist state managing a dense urban population. Effective bureaucracy, public housing, and urban planning enabled development. However, Singapore remains dominated by one party and the founding Lee dynasty, with limited press freedoms or civil liberties. Its small geographic size as a city-state makes governance inherently less complex than China’s vast territory and population. Singapore also exists within a stable regional context unlike China’s historical turbulence and geopolitical rivalries.

Other East Asian developmental states like South Korea, Taiwan and Japan exercised strong state capacity while allowing greater openness and media oversight. They avoided highly centralized power under one leader. Their consensus-based policymaking brought more voices into decisions. These systems sustained flexibility and economic dynamism with power changing between competing political parties over time. Excessive concentration of power enables mistakes or rigidity. Distributed governance can stimulate innovation across society.

Urbanization and development in democratic societies like India and Brazil highlight different tradeoffs. Democracy better represents diverse interests and fosters innovation through decentralization. However, fragmented politics also enables gridlock and localized corruption. Development in democracies may be messy and uneven across regions. But active civil society provides feedback and support for the poor. Long-term progress results more from open information flows than top-down control. Suppression of criticism risks instability when citizens inevitably speak out against abuses.

Overall, China’s centralized development model reached its limits even while market reforms continue. Sustaining progress through the middle income trap requires additional opening and adaption of the political system. Concentration of power risks stagnation and conflict when complex modern societies need flexibility, accountability and new ideas to advance. China faces a dilemma between maintaining regime control and unleashing the full innovative potential of its people.

Conclusions

China’s unique political system enabled watershed development feats including rapid industrialization, mass urbanization and infrastructure modernization across the world’s largest population. Authoritarian governance allowed forceful execution of market reforms and long-term plans. State capacity mobilized resources across provinces for major projects and strategic investments. Relaxing social control brought sufficient flexibility to defuse pressures and maintain stability while driving growth. Steadily improving living standards bolstered CCP legitimacy.

However, China’s political model now confronts limits as easy growth phases end. Challenges such as inequality, environmental damage, demographic decline, economic risks and middle income trap pressures are mounting. An increasingly sophisticated public expects better services, transparency, legal rights and accountability beyond just material gains. The social compact depends on continued advancement. Xi’s strongman expansion of power could reduce flexibility to address complex challenges in a diverse, modern society. Excessive stability maintenance creates tensions and risks instability over the long-term.

Sustaining progress requires more inclusive, responsive governance and loosening political control over society and the economy to spur innovation. Additional reforms and transparency are essential as growth slows. Adaptability, decentralization and civil society participation will gain importance. Concentrated CCP power may prove too rigid for China’s volatile transition to an advanced nation in a swiftly changing world. The coming decade will test whether the current political model can renew itself while maintaining stability. If not, pressures for democratic transition may inexorably rise.

References

Banister, J., & Hill, K. (2004). Mortality in China 1964–2000. Population Studies, 58(1), 55-75.

Bell, D. A. (2015). The China model: Political meritocracy and the limits of democracy. Princeton University Press.

Biswas, S. (2018). Why China’s high debt levels are sustainable. BBC News. https://www.bbc.com/news/business-45674244

Cai, F., & Lu, Y. (2013). Population change and resulting slowdown in potential GDP growth in China. China & World Economy, 21(2), 1-14.

Chen, J. (2016). Stability and legitimacy: China’s leadership challenge in the twenty-first century. The Chinese Journal of Sociology, 2(3), 337-359.

Economy, E. C. (2018). The third revolution: Xi Jinping and the new Chinese state. Oxford University Press.

Halper, S. (2010). The Beijing consensus: How China’s authoritarian model will dominate the twenty-first century. Basic Books.

Heilmann, S. (2017). China’s political system and its future trajectory. Strategic Review, 6(4).

Heilmann, S., & Stepan, M. (2016). China’s core executive: Leadership styles, structures and processes under Xi Jinping. Mercator Institute for China Studies.

Kania, E. B. (2018). Made in China 2025, explained. The Diplomat. https://thediplomat.com/2018/02/made-in-china-2025-explained/

Lawrence, S. V., & Martin, M. F. (2013). Understanding China’s political system. Congressional Research Service.

Li, S., & Wan, G. (2015). Evolution of wealth inequality in China. China Economic Journal, 8(3), 264-287.

Peng, X. (2011). China’s demographic history and future challenges. Science, 333(6042), 581-587.

Trevaskes, S. (2010). Policing contentious politics in China. The China Quarterly, 205, 403-421.

Truex, R. (2016). Making autocracy work: Representation and responsiveness in modern China. Cambridge University Press.

Wang, Y. (2017). The dynamics of welfare and population change: Explaining pension underfunding in China’s cities. The China Quarterly, 230, 349-374.

World Bank. (2019). The World Bank in China. https://www.worldbank.org/en/country/china/overview

5/5 - (39 votes)

SAKHRI Mohamed

I hold a bachelor's degree in political science and international relations as well as a Master's degree in international security studies, alongside a passion for web development. During my studies, I gained a strong understanding of key political concepts, theories in international relations, security and strategic studies, as well as the tools and research methods used in these fields.

Leave a Comment